Peru OUTSTANDING ISSUES
At a bus stop in downtown Lima
Courtesy Inter-American Development Bank
Unavailable
Figure 11. Employment by Sector, 1990
Children in La Molina, a town south of Lima
Courtesy Inter-American Development Bank
Harvesting hay near Huancayo, Junín Department
CourtesyHarvesting hay near Huancayo, Junín Department
Miner about to enter the 4,000-meter-high Mina Proaño
multimineral mine
CourtesyMiner about to enter the 4,000-meter-high Mina Proaño
multimineral mine
Miners drill dynamite holes at the Mina Raúl open-pit
copper mine near Arequipa
Courtesy Inter-American Development Bank
For many Peruvians, the frustrations of prolonged
economic
deterioration in the face of such varied attempts to do
something
about it mean that something fundamental has gone wrong,
perhaps
so wrong that mere changes of public policy can do little
to
help. Such fears are certainly understandable and also
costly.
They encourage support for violent reaction, and they also
foster
great pressure on each new government to act quickly, in
dramatic
new ways, without sufficient attention to the likely costs
of
their actions. Such pressure may be a key part of the
problem.
Issues of current policy orientation need to be considered
in the
perspective of Peru's extremely dislocated society, but
that
context argues for great caution, as well as for change.
The
specific issues center on familiar conflicts: between the
appeal
of trying to return to the open economy and liberal
economic
system preceding the 1960s, and the contrary appeal of a
more
directive use of public policy to correct basic structural
problems.
Convictions that something fundamental has gone wrong
with
the country can lead to violence, to emigration as an
escape, or
possibly instead to new consensus on the need to change
particular constraints of public policy. The SL has
advocated an
extreme answer: traditional society has failed and needs
to be
swept away. For many others who reject violence, the
answer has
not seemed to be much more positive: emigration has become
an
increasingly popular way out for many, including
professional
people and businesspeople who take their capital with
them.
Although it is truly difficult to be certain that a
reasonably
peaceful recovery remains possible, two alternative
answers, in
different ways, suggest somewhat more hope for the future.
One interpretation of the deterioration since the
mid-1960s
is that it has been caused by stubbornly misdirected
economic
policies, specifically excessive protection for import
substitution, a proliferation of internal controls adverse
to
efficiency and free markets, government deficits, and
wildly
exaggerated monetary expansion. That position gains solid
support
from the results of the governments of Velasco and García,
plus
much of the administration under Belaúnde. In that light,
the
Fujimori government's return of national policy to an open
economy with greatly reduced protection and controls and
more
attention to budget balance is genuinely hopeful. The
redirection
initially offered the promise of renewed external help
from
international financial and development agencies, although
that
possibility was set back at least temporarily in April
1992 when
the Fujimori government suspended democracy in Peru.
A second nonviolent alternative goes against attempts
to
return to the kind of economic system Peru had prior to
the
1960s. The old system was neither an equitable system that
served
to integrate the society nor one that favored learning and
technical progress. The depth of Peru's problems in 1991
seemed
to call for more directive economic strategies to lessen
poverty,
pull the industrial sector into export competition, and
establish
a stronger tax base to provide noninflationary financing
for an
active government. Such redirection would be fully
consistent
with reduced protection, although it would gain from
adding on
strong incentives for industrial exports. It would need
much the
same kind of effort to maintain fiscal balance as the
first
alternative, although more through higher public revenue
and less
through cutback of public-sector functions.
Both of these two alternative orientations raise
serious
questions about what is possible. Such questions might be
considered on three levels: first, can economic growth be
revived
without making inflation accelerate again; second, can the
spread
and deepening of poverty be reversed; and third, can the
Peruvian
people regain enough confidence in their society to induce
renewed investment, productive effort, and acceptance of
the
constraints necessary to rebuild?
To the question on the first level, it is certainly no
easy
matter to revive economic growth without provoking
inflation
again, given all the special handicaps of political
uncertainty,
growing violence, and intense public awareness of past
failures
to curb inflation. Still, nearly all the purely economic
conditions for revival without inflation are present: the
industrial sector has a great deal of underutilized
capacity,
both skilled and unskilled labor is available in
abundance, and
the country is in the unusual position of having abundant
supplies of foreign exchange to finance increased imports
of
supplies needed for rising production. If investment and
exports
can be encouraged, it should be possible to raise
production
quickly, without running into any near-term limitations on
the
supply side.
The experience of the first two years of the García
government, from 1985 to 1987, suggests both the scope for
raising output in such conditions and the danger of doing
too
much, too rapidly. That experience does not point to any
necessary relapse back into inflation: it simply
underlines the
need for methods that are more consistent and more
careful. The
García government's revival was crippled quickly because
of
particular choices that could have been avoided. The
exchange-
rate policy was wholly and unnecessarily misdirected. More
fundamentally, the degree of stimulus lacked any clear
relationship to the constraints on how much it was
possible to
do, how fast, and with what financing. The need for
adequate tax
revenue and the need for prices of government services
adequate
to cover costs were never faced. To pay more attention to
internal and external macroeconomic balance would have
required a
slower pace of expansion, but it might then have been
possible to
keep going without explosion. The experience does not
demonstrate
that sustained recovery is practically impossible in Peru,
only
that it has to be done with extreme care because of the
damage of
past misjudgment.
To the question on the second level--the possibility of
seriously reducing poverty--the experience under García
again
suggests both grounds for hope and reasons for doubt. That
government's combination of measures was initially
favorable for
both the rural poor and those in the informal urban
sector. These
measures made a notable dent in the degree of extreme
poverty in
the first two years. If the overall expansion had been
more
moderate, the gains would have been less but still
positive.
Redirection of public investment and of credit toward the
rural
sector must have played a helpful role in that brief
experience
of reducing poverty and inequality, as they would under
any
government if placed within a framework of overall
balance.
Promotion of a more labor-intensive structure of
production,
with more rapidly growing employment opportunities for any
given
level of investment, could do a great deal to lessen
poverty and
inequality in the longer run. A necessary condition to
move in
this direction is to avoid overvaluation of the exchange
rate.
Overvaluation hurts the poor by making imported capital
equipment
and supplies artificially inexpensive, and thereby
encouraging
the replacement of workers with machinery. This situation
took
place under García, Velasco, and Belaúnde. Overvaluation
is not
beyond correction by a government concerned with the
problem,
although it may require intervention to offset perverse
market
forces like those operating in the first year of the
Fujimori
government. The price of foreign exchange needs to be kept
high
enough to encourage growth of industrial exports, or else
more
specific measures have to be taken to keep them growing,
even if
this means intervening to change the way that market
forces are
operating.
Beyond such questions of differential incentives and
employment opportunities, and of investment and credit for
the
rural area, serious action to alleviate poverty clearly
requires
a strong public commitment to provide more nearly equal
access to
education, to public health programs directed to the poor,
and to
social action to alleviate conditions of mass hunger. The
problem
with the alternative of going back to an open economy with
much
less of a role for government is that it could leave the
extent
of poverty as great as ever, or even discourage public
action to
do more about it. Velasco and García went wrong in many
ways, but
their efforts to change the society were attempts to
respond to a
real need. To go back to the pre-1960s kind of economic
regime
might well be less costly than to repeat the nightmares of
1988-
90, but it would leave the human problems of Peru
unresolved.
To the question on the third level--the possibility of
restored confidence in the society--the answer cannot be
in terms
of economic analysis. It may be that the shocks of the
1980s and
those of 1990, combined with the worsening of violence and
deterioration of the capability of the government to act,
will
make it difficult for a long time to generate rising
investment,
whether by Peruvians or foreign investors. It may be that
fear of
inflation will paralyze promotional action by the
government or,
alternatively, that long delay will generate overwhelming
pressures for violent change. Such possibilities are all
too
real. But the surge of hope in 1985-86 (and the surge of
investment and of production that immediately came with
it) made
fatalism about Peru seem misplaced. Even through the
confusions
of economic policy at that time, including a great many
costly
kinds of interference adverse to efficiency, and even in
the face
of destructive violence, Peru was able to respond
positively to
the temporary turn in a more promising direction.
Production went
up, poverty went down, and the reign of terror in the
Sierra
temporarily lessened. Both poverty and violence were worse
in
1991, but the background of economic policy distortions
had in
part been corrected.
It is probably true that Peru has a fundamental problem
that
underlies the long downward trend of its economic
performance. It
is not just the misdirection of excessive protection,
government
intervention, and excess spending. It is the severity of
poverty
and inequality. Too many people have serious grounds to
reject
the society because it has done so little to provide them
any
hope. The governments since the mid-1960s all tried to
find some
new way to deal with this basic weakness. Their methods
were
terribly damaging. It is fairly easy to see what went
wrong in
each case, if not so easy to see how to work out the
interlocking
problems at the beginning of the 1990s. Recovery of
production is
surely possible with better designed economic policies,
but to
keep society intact requires that the government go beyond
reactivation of the economy to include more effective ways
to
reduce poverty on a sustained basis.
* * *
The Peruvian Experiment, edited by Abraham F.
Lowenthal, and The Peruvian Experiment
Reconsidered,
edited by Cynthia McClintock and Lowenthal, cover the
Velasco
period and its consequences. Rosemary Thorp and Geoffrey
Bertram's Peru 1890-1977 is a comprehensive
economic
history. Paul E. Gootenberg's Between Silver and
Guano
examines the roles of nationalism and liberalism in
shaping the
country's development.
On agrarian problems, consult Tom Alberts's Agrarian
Reform and Rural Poverty and Adolfo Figueroa's
Capitalist
Development and the Peasant Economy in Peru. On the
informal
sector, the classic book is Hernando de Soto's The
Other
Path.
The García government's economic program from 1985 to
1990 is
analyzed in Eva Paus, "Adjustment and Development in Latin
America," and in Manuel Pastor, Jr. and Carol Wise,
"Peruvian
Economic Policy in the 1980s." Thorp's Economic
Management and
Economic Development in Peru and Colombia examines
this
period through a comparison of the ways the two countries
have
managed their long-term problems of development. Peru's
Path
to Recovery, edited by Carlos E. Paredes and Jeffrey
D.
Sachs, is a thorough survey of Peru's problems at the
start of
the Fujimori government in 1990, with many proposals for
corrective action. Particularly useful monthly Peruvian
publications include The Andean Report and Perú
Económico. (For further information and complete
citations,
see
Bibliography.)
Data as of September 1992
|